Comparative advantage is associated with 19th Century English economist David Ricardo. Ricardo suggested that countries should specialise in producing goods and services for which they have a comparative advantage. While an ‘absolute’ advantage means one country is more cost-efficient than another, comparative advantage relates to the extent to which one country is more efficient. Let’s look at a simple example.
Consider two countries producing only two goods – milk or sugar. Using all its resources, country A can produce 4m litres of milk or 10 tonnes of sugar. Country B can produce 8m litres of milk or 12 tonnes of sugar. We will assume that 1 million litres of milk is equal to 2 tonnes of sugar in terms of value – let’s say each is worth $200,000. Clearly, B is better at both and has an absolute advantage over A. So, should they trade?
Well, in comparative terms B has an advantage in terms of milk – it is 100% more productive in milk, but only 20% better at sugar production, so, in terms of the principle of comparative advantage, they should trade - with B specialising in milk leaving A to produce sugar. Lets look at this.
If they specialise and then trade, world output will be 18 units (Milk = 8, sugar = 10): However, if they divide up their resources to produce both, then they can produce half of the maximum for both products - and total output will be 17 units. (Milk 2 + 4, and sugar, 5 + 6).
The relative value of world output is: $2.6m with specialisation and trade, and: $2.3m without self-sufficiency.
Graphically, the gradient of the PPF reflects the opportunity cost of production - different gradients mean different opportunity costs ratios, and hence specialisation and trade will be beneficial.